When A. H. Greenspan Talks Markets
(Don’t) Listen
Martin Harris
Martin
Harris is an architect and former farmer.
It was a great little TV ad in its day. At a country club’s
open-air lunch tables, pools and tennis court in background, one
silver-haired retiree/investor confides to another: “E. F. Hutton says
that XYZ stock
” He never finishes the sentence: other
country-clubbers set aside their gin-and-tonic glasses to cup their ears
and eavesdrop. The message: Hutton can move markets and thus make money
for clients. You, viewer, should become one. The problem: brokerage
houses are supposed to be investing in markets, not moving them.
The
Federal Reserve is supposed to be moving them: as needed, to stabilize
the currency, because the U.S. Congress didn’t want the task as set
forth in the U.S. Constitution (Article1, Section 8: to coin money and
regulate the value thereof) any more after failing at the job with the
First and Second Banks of the United States. By the late 19th century
Wall Street bankers were, for all practical purposes, controlling and
stabilizing what had been a patchwork of currencies, and so in 1913
Congress simply formalized the arrangement by setting up a Federal
Reserve System to do what Congress couldn’t or wouldn’t.
And how well has the Fed done its job? I’ll report, you decide.
Here are the numbers. In the 124 years from 1789 to1913, when the dollar
was being managed by the Congress, Nicholas Biddle, Andrew Jackson, Abe
Lincoln, and Wall Street bankers, it depreciated 12 percent. You would
have needed $1.12 in 1913 to buy what $1 bought at the Nation’s
founding. In the 90 years of Fed management, 1913 to 2003, it has
depreciated 94.5 percent. You need $18.08 now to buy what $1 bought the
year after the Titanic sank. $1 is 5.5 percent of $18.08.
And
why has the Fed not done any better? After all, nations around the globe
stabilize their money against a market basket of commodities and
services, using the mathematical functions of a currency board to make
sure a British pound, or whatever, has the same purchasing power this
year as last. The answer, of course, is that it doesn’t want to do
better. As our own domestic inflation rate approached zero in recent
years, the Fed has stepped in—to prevent deflation, they say—with a
series of interest rates cuts to increase borrowing and thus the
quantity of money in circulation: more money chasing the same goods, or
inflation. The Fed’s goal, it says, is “modest” inflation, not
currency stabilization.
And
why inflation? Unlike the above facts, this is opinion: because, in a
nation of voter-debtors, politicians (and Fed Governors) who like their
well-paid jobs will always make sure that debt service will be easy
(with depreciated dollars) rather than hard, with full-value or even
appreciated dollars.
And
where did they learn this lesson? From American agriculture, more
precisely the mid-Western farmers of the post-Civil War decades of
continuous monetary deflation, getting deeper in debt as crops declined
in value against an ever-stronger dollar. The Populist near-rebellion,
with the slogan of “free-silver” simply a respectable way of
demanding cheaper money through inflation, shook the establishment of
the day: at a time in history when neither the Nation nor most
individuals had any debt, they were caught unawares when a swing-vote
bloc, homesteaders, suddenly changed the rules and demanded an
ever-cheapening dollar. Now everyone’s in debt, and, not surprisingly,
the Fed accommodates: we promise you controlled inflation, Alan
Greenspan, Fed Chairman, now says.
Back
then, of course, agriculture mattered: the farm population was still
well over half the total, and it’s less than two percent today. But
today, urbanites and governments as well are in debt, which is why
deflation is now unthinkable, stabilization not good enough, and
inflation a desired goal for those supposedly charged with, as Fed
Governor Ben Bernanke says, “achieving and maintaining price
stability.” To make sure the dollar stays mildly inflationary, Alan
Greenspan’s Fed has cut overnight deposit interest rates to one
percent (only two years ago the Federal funds target rate was at six
percent) But guess what—Mr. Greenspan apparently lacks Mr. Hutton’s
charisma, and, for the first time in Fed history, the bond market itself
isn’t listening. Bond buyers aren’t buying bonds; indeed, they’re
selling, bond prices are dropping, and therefore interest rates are
climbing. If you’ve priced mortgages recently you know.
And
if you have no mortgage, you don’t much care. If you own bonds, they’ll
fall in value as rates climb. If you want to buy land, equipment, or
both on credit, now’s the time to act because, historically, interest
rates are still quite low. Here’s my point: since 1789, Americans have
been promised a government which would “regulate” the value of
money. Since 1913, Americans have been promised a Fed which would “stabilize”
the dollar. Since 1978, Americans have believed that the Fed could do
the job: under Paul Volcker in the early ‘80s, it ended double-digit
inflation and since then has apparently been able to fine-tune our
financial structure through interest-rate manipulations, supposedly in
pursuit of currency stabilization. Now we know different.
Now we know that the Fed’s goal isn’t stabilization at all,
but rather inflation in the 2-3 percent range. For anyone in debt, that’s
good news: it means that, say, a 6 percent note costs him only 3
percent. And we also know that what the Fed wants, it won’t always
get. Not only have recent rate cuts failed to move the markets, but more
importantly, the Fed is running out of maneuver room: it has only a
single percentage point of influence left. When rates are at or near
zero, as they have been in Japan recently, how then can government
stimulate the economy? Short answer: it can’t, at least not with the
usual monetary-policy tools. It’s not being said in polite circles
(country-club lunch tables, for example) but I’d suggest that the Fed
is suffering an enormous credibility decline. Will Congress take back
the job? I doubt it. Is deflation of the 1865-1895 type possible? I’d
say yes, with all it’s nasty implications for debtors; but then
farmers have already been experiencing crop-value-deflation, just like
their great-grandparents, all through recent decades,
and the Fed hasn’t cared a whit. It was only when deflation began to
cast urban shadows that Greenspan and company became concerned.
If
Greenspan and the Fed aren’t effectively guiding national monetary
policy, who and what is? I’d say the market is: that multitude of
individual decisions on savings, investment, purchases, loans which, in
sum, make up Adam Smith’s “invisible hand.” As in J. P. Morgan’s
time, we’re back in a situation where the marketplace, not would-be
economic commanders, controls the value of the dollar. (As it did,
pretty much, up to 1913.) In short, whether we have deflation,
stability, or inflation, now depends on the decisions of all of us, not
of Mr. Greenspan and his Open Market Committee. Is this a good thing?
Here’s
the comment of Daniel McFadden, vineyard operator, UCAL-Berkeley
economics professor, and Nobel laureate:
The
history of government regulation of markets is littered with examples of
restrictions, ostensibly adopted on behalf of consumers, that instead
protect concentrated economic interests.
I
agree. Ω