|
Why Cities?
Martin HarrisMartin
Harris lives in Brandon, VT. He is an architect, and a property rights and
education advocate. In all the “blue” states, Vermont
included, downtown preservation (with mandatory anti-sprawl, smart-growth
regulation and taxpayer subsidy as needed) is an article of faith among the
socially and environmentally enlightened. They will tolerate no thought of an
alternative. But there is one. It’s based on the obvious technological
and economic facts which have made the typical old-style city, high-intensity
land use, high population density, difficult to supply with essential utilities
and to enable the handling of freight and commodities--as obsolete as the
defensive walls which once surrounded its urban-design ancestors. Some European cities—Tallinn and Carcassonne--have restored their walls to attract tourists, but there’s
little they or any typical 19th or 20th century city can do to meet,
efficiently, the logistical demands and the communications opportunities which
now favor non-urban-center, low-density commercial and industrial development. The New York Stock
Exchange could as well reside in the city of Manhattan, Kansas, as in the
Borough of Manhattan, New York, NY. With electronic trading soon to replace the
open-outcry auction floor system, there’s no need for its thousands of
staffers to suffer the underground commute to Broad and Wall Streets when they
could as easily drive to a verdant campus on the perimeter of the Riley County
seat. In fact, with electronic trading, the NYSE could become virtual, spread
across all 105 of Kansas’ counties, each trader working from his home
terminal with no commute at all; think of the energy-conservation. The idea that urban
centers are becoming obsolete (just as their defensive walls did four to five
hundred years ago, which explains why there’s no longer a wall at Wall
Street) doesn’t set well with important people. Urban planners and academics,
activists and politicians, all cling fast to the idea that cities in their
present form will always be essential, even if, increasingly, they need outside
subsidy to survive and pretend to compete. The NYSE, for example,
has floated the threat of abandoning downtown NYC each time it wants a new tax
abatement or other subsidy from local and state government. Each time
it’s worked, which explains why you still have to endure the subway ride
to get to its 1903 headquarters. Only ordinary
citizens, in their massive post-WWII flight from American cities to the suburbs
and beyond (e.g., to Vermont) challenge the concept of cities-forever, and even
they do so with their feet and not their voices (except when they’re
polled, after which their overwhelmingly Jeffersonian anti-city sentiment is
always discounted by the supposed experts). I’ve written
perhaps a score of times over the years on the “why-cities?
question,” and each time my thesis, that urban-obsolescence is well under
way, irreversible, and to be welcomed rather than resisted has provoked more
response than any other subject my columns address. A recent effort in the Addison
County Eagle (VT) was no exception:
it brought calls ranging from full agreement to full disagreement, and an
e-mail from a Weybridge exurbanite (in relation to metropolitan Middlebury,
population 8000, that is) suggesting that I “wouldn’t be missed in
[downtown] Middlebury.” He’s quite
right, except for my spending (such as it is) which would be missed, which in
turns explains why the downtown businessmen felt compelled to run a
customer-satisfaction survey recently in Middlebury’s other newspaper,
the Independent. Downtown Middlebury is
in economic trouble for the usual reason: all the serious commerce has migrated
to the lower-development-density perimeter. Downtown stores are increasingly
highly specialized boutiques catering to a fancy-driven, exurban, upper-income
customer base. There used to be many
reasons for cities: military, theological, economic. Face-to-face contact with
peers was a reason, and still is, but now businessmen and scientists hold their
conferences at airport hotels far outside the urban center, because--although
my Weybridge critic (a retired academic, judging from his udel.edu e-mail
address) decries it as me-ism--convenience and efficiency matter to people who
actually work. Industry now builds its plants in open
country, serious commerce needs space to park customers’ cars and trucks,
and the old buildings for such former downtown functions as warehousing and distribution
are now tourist hotels and expensive condominiums. Americans don’t
build cities for military or theological reasons: Fort Riley (KS) is well
outside Manhattan, not surrounding it. Even Salt Lake City (UT) is today far
more economic than evangelical. (And in trouble, economically.) When we build
for government purposes, look at national Social Security headquarters in
Maryland: it’s miles outside downtown Baltimore (which needs more help
than it gets, anyway, since the middle class fled to the suburbs and exurbs following
the riots of the ‘60s.) Planners and
psychologists haven’t figured out how to get Americans out of their cars
for business, except in a few artificial situations like Michigan’s
Detroit Renaissance Center, or Vermont’s Burlington Church Street
pedestrian-only conversion, both the products of outside subsidy. Indeed,
supposedly “free” (taxpayer-funded) in-town buses run their loops
nearly empty, typically, which explains why most are fitted with tinted
windows. We in the architecture/planning
industry have our theories but we don’t know for sure why shoppers will
willingly walk a few hundred yards from parking to store at a mall but
won’t willingly do the same distance downtown. Some cities and larger
villages recognize and encourage low-density commerce, as Middlebury did, quite
well, when designing and building a campus-style industrial/commercial park on
outlying Exchange Street, but quite poorly on Route 7 South, where the town
fathers used federal grant money to facilitate just the sort of strip
development they now decry. Those urban centers
will keep some economic viability; those which demand that everything be
downtown, as it all once was, won’t. Fundamentally, there’s just no
compelling reason any more for 21st century people to try to function in a19th
century (or earlier) environment, and they’re, we’re, not willing
to sacrifice productivity and convenience to do so. Should we, then,
preserve and restore our downtowns, or let them decline in density to the point
where they can match the out-of-town grey zones in occupant efficiency (Los
Angeles has moved in this direction) by not opposing antique building
destruction? Yes, if local voters wish to do the subsidizing; no, if they
don’t. There are, of course, national historic landmarks in a few
downtowns, deserving of national-taxpayer preservation spending, but most
ordinary places like Middlebury don’t have any. We local taxpayers
here shouldn’t be demanding that earners in the Midwest be forced, under
ultimate threat of lethal legal force, to chip in for preserving our antique
structures, any more than we here should be forced to chip in for comparable
efforts in, say, Stillwater (MN) by the St. Croix River. What will happen in a free-market situation is that
some urban centers (like Tallinn and Carcassonne, New Orleans and Savannah)
will tax themselves to preserve their antiquities and to profit therefrom, and
some won’t. Some places, like Los Angeles, will rebuild themselves by
slow and not always architecturally handsome stages into the low-density city
of the future envisioned by architect Frank Lloyd Wright in his proposals for a
“Broadacre City” urban model. There will be efforts,
like Reston (VA) to build new cities, on the new model, from scratch. All these
are to be encouraged. What’s to be discouraged is the willful decision of
a few who consider themselves opinion-shapers to force on everyone else their
particular vision: no permissible alternative to the high-density urban model
which has prevailed for about eight millennia but now seems about to become
irrelevant. * “The right to be left alone is indeed the beginning of all freedoms.” –William Douglas |
||
[ Who We Are | Authors | Archive | Subscription | Search | Contact Us ] © Copyright St.Croix Review 2002 |