|
Regulating Corporate Governance:
The Magic of the Marketplace
Murray Weidenbaum
Murray Weidenbaum holds the Mallinckrodt Distinguished University
Professorship at Washington University where he is also honorary
chairman of the Weidenbaum Center on the Economy, Government, and Public
Policy. This speech was a presentation to the Conference on Corporate
Governance, Washington University. Financial markets, regulation, and business management
interact in a variety of ways. Let us begin by trying to disentangle
these three interrelated variables. To start, I suggest that the impacts
of financial markets on business decision making are fundamental and
well known. By purchasing a corporation’s stocks and bonds,
participants in financial markets provide the long-term capital that
finances the activities of the enterprise. Examples of the
disciplinary features of financial markets are commonplace. Poor
financial performance makes it more difficult and costly for the
enterprise to sell its bonds. For the more capital-intensive companies
that issue debt regularly, notably utilities, this is a continuing
source of concern to senior executives and it influences a host of
everyday decisions. Likewise, for any publicly held company, it is the
rare member of the management that cannot tell you the current price of
the company’s stock—and that does not mean something as ancient as
yesterday’s closing price. To the holders of significant blocks of
stocks and/or options, such information is compelling. So is it to
executives whose current compensation depends in part on the performance
of the company’s stock. From a broader
viewpoint, changes in the price of a company’s stock can have many
repercussions on business decision making. A rising stock price
lubricates acquisitions and makes new stock offerings more attractive.
It also helps to keep shareholders happy. Conversely, a poorly
performing stock restricts corporate discretion. It also arouses
shareholders and it may make the company more vulnerable to a hostile
takeover. Finally, any doubters of the influence of financial
markets on business decision making should recall the recurrent
criticism of the short-term orientation of American business. Critics
claim that too much—rather than too little—management attention is
focused on actions that could raise the stock price in the next quarter
or two. We can even recall instances where extraordinary compensation
was promised to top management if the company’s common stock would
reach a designated price for just a 10-day period. That may be the
epitome of focusing management attention on financial markets. The
adoption of such compensation practices surely raises serious issues of
corporate governance. Let us now turn to the
role of government regulation. We are in the midst of an unusually rapid
expansion of federal involvement in corporate governance. As a long-term
corporate director, I feel impelled to report a personal attitude that
departs considerably from the views that we economists hold on the
subject of regulation. Just for the record, I
have devoted a substantial portion of my academic research to evaluating
the impacts of regulation on American business, especially
manufacturing. Early on, I advocated the introduction of benefit/cost
analysis to screen proposed regulations. This approach enables the
analyst to take an ostensibly neutral position, giving equal weight to
the benefits and the costs. I did learn that, if you are in the middle
of the road, you will be hit by traffic going in both directions. As a board member,
however, I instinctively view regulatory requirements in a negative
light, as an annoying and unhelpful intrusion. As a practical matter, I
lean heavily on the general counsel and the chief financial officer to
keep the bureaucrats at bay—so that we directors can continue to
exercise our independent and informed judgment on the important issues
facing the board and the company. To clear the air, the desired result is not passivity
on the part of the board. Having led the ouster of the CEOs of two large
companies, I may have a different view of the boardroom than others.
Surely, there are serious matters that directors face in dealing with
the chairman and the management—especially when the two roles are
combined. My point is that I do not find government officials helpful in
that process. In any event,
regulation is a rising influence on corporate governance. Surely, if the
requirements imposed by the Sarbanes-Oxley bill result in substantially
greater confidence in the financial reporting of American business, the
results may well justify the added costs being imposed. I remain a
skeptic, however, because I believe that the Enron experience had a
greater—and more positive—impact. Indeed, Enron continues to be a
presence in many boardrooms today. No director wants to suffer the fate
of the Enron directors who were tossed off other boards just because
they wore the Enron badge of shame. Advocates of more
governmental intrusion in corporate governance tend to ignore the
demonstrated ability of private enterprise to reform itself. As I
recall, the initial requirement for a board to have an audit committee
of outside directors came, not from the governmental securities
regulators, but from the New York Stock Exchange. Also, following
substantial criticism, most boards of larger corporations voluntarily
shifted their composition to a heavy majority of outside (albeit not
necessarily independent) directors. I remain a skeptic of
the effectiveness of government regulation for reasons that go beyond
the area of corporate governance. Unlike the familiar tools of
government expenditure and revenue, regulation is politically popular
because it does not involve significant amounts of federal resources.
The substantial compliance costs generated by regulation are buried in
business financial and operating reports. I refer to the hidden tax of
regulation, which is thus also off-budget. As politicians occasionally
admit, “The best tax is a hidden tax.” Regulation frequently generates adverse side effects
and Sarbanes-Oxley (SOX) is no exception. Several foreign companies have
taken action to avoid the hidden tax imposed by the new statute. They
have done so by withdrawing their shares from trading in the United
States and also have withdrawn their registration with the Security and
Exchange Commission (SEC). Perhaps a far greater side effect of the
recent expansion in government regulation of corporate governance is the
tendency of some companies to go private. Also, some investment advisers
urge their wealthy clients to avoid serving on corporate boards. Their
concern relates to the rising liability facing directors. This situation is
compounded by a loophole in the normal regulatory review process. Like
other independent regulatory commissions, the SEC is exempt from the
requirement for federal agencies to do a benefit/cost analysis prior to
promulgating a new regulation. Hence, there may be more than a remote
possibility that the costs imposed by the regulations issued pursuant to
SOX exceed the benefits generated. Some indirect evidence is provided by the studies of the relationship between board composition and company performance. These studies in general do not support the implicit assumption underlying SOX. There is no impressive body of evidence demonstrating that outside directors enhance company performance. Perhaps that should not be surprising. After all, Enron’s board likely met the Sarbanes-Oxley requirements with flying colors. I must report that ostensibly independent outside
directors at times can rubber stamp management proposals while some
inside directors can exert their independence. In earlier years, when
inside dominated boards were commonplace, the compensation of CEOs was
less dramatically large and closer to that of other members of
management. To complete this
analysis, I submit that one of the lessons learned from earlier
regulatory statutes is that, sooner or later, companies learn how to
adjust to and comply with regulatory requirements. They build such
compliance into their operating procedures. Like any other cost it
faces, management tries to minimize it and sometimes learns how to get
around the law and regulations. This leads us back to the powerful and
continuing role of financial markets in disciplining corporate decision
making. Does the overall
process of relying primarily on the pressures of the market work
effectively? The answer is clear. Compare the performance of American
business with that of other advanced industrial economies. Over the
years, we outperform Western Europe and Japan—in production,
profitability, and job creation. It is a tribute to what Ronald Reagan
called “The Magic of the Marketplace.”
* “When those who are governed do too little, those who govern can—and often will—do to much.” Ronald Reagan |
||
[ Who We Are | Authors | Archive | Subscription | Search | Contact Us ] © Copyright St.Croix Review 2002 |